Trade and empire

Kevin O'Rourke

Research output: Chapter in Book/Report/Conference proceedingChapter

Abstract

Introduction: the rise and fall of European mercantilism At the start of the first millennium, western Europe was the most peripheral region in Eurasia. Like Africa, its exports largely consisted of forest products and slaves, and it had direct economic links with just two other Eurasian regions – eastern Europe and the Islamic world. By contrast, the Islamic world had direct economic contacts with all the regions of the then known world: eastern and western Europe, sub-Saharan Africa, the steppe societies of central Asia, and the highly developed civilizations of south Asia, southeast Asia, and east Asia (Findlay and O'Rourke, 2007). By the eighteenth century, western Europe was no longer a peripheral appendage of the Eurasian landmass, but had become geographically and politically central. It was now in direct contact with all other regions of Eurasia, as well as with sub-Saharan Africa, but more importantly it controlled both North and South America, which were fully integrated into the world economy, importing slaves from Africa, exporting a variety of colonial goods to Europe, and exporting silver both to Europe and to Asia via the Philippines. As for eastern Europe, it was now in direct contact not just with central Asia and the Muslim world, but with east Asia and North America as well, as a result of Russia's Siberian conquests, which would prove to be the most enduring of all the European imperialisms of that time.

Original languageEnglish (US)
Title of host publicationThe Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1
Subtitle of host publication1700-1870
PublisherCambridge University Press
Pages96-121
Number of pages26
ISBN (Electronic)9780511794834
ISBN (Print)9780521882026
DOIs
StatePublished - Jan 1 2010

Fingerprint

Eastern Europe
Economics
East Asia
Islamic World
Africa
Sub-Saharan Africa
Central Asia
Eurasia
Slaves
Controlled
Colonies
Philippines
South Asia
Civilization
Asia
Conquest
World Economy
Steppe
South-East Asia
Rise

ASJC Scopus subject areas

  • Arts and Humanities(all)

Cite this

O'Rourke, K. (2010). Trade and empire. In The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1: 1700-1870 (pp. 96-121). Cambridge University Press. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511794834.006

Trade and empire. / O'Rourke, Kevin.

The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1: 1700-1870. Cambridge University Press, 2010. p. 96-121.

Research output: Chapter in Book/Report/Conference proceedingChapter

O'Rourke, K 2010, Trade and empire. in The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1: 1700-1870. Cambridge University Press, pp. 96-121. https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511794834.006
O'Rourke K. Trade and empire. In The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1: 1700-1870. Cambridge University Press. 2010. p. 96-121 https://doi.org/10.1017/CBO9780511794834.006
O'Rourke, Kevin. / Trade and empire. The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1: 1700-1870. Cambridge University Press, 2010. pp. 96-121
@inbook{7d679195d77a4cafb494a2d5119fa9cd,
title = "Trade and empire",
abstract = "Introduction: the rise and fall of European mercantilism At the start of the first millennium, western Europe was the most peripheral region in Eurasia. Like Africa, its exports largely consisted of forest products and slaves, and it had direct economic links with just two other Eurasian regions – eastern Europe and the Islamic world. By contrast, the Islamic world had direct economic contacts with all the regions of the then known world: eastern and western Europe, sub-Saharan Africa, the steppe societies of central Asia, and the highly developed civilizations of south Asia, southeast Asia, and east Asia (Findlay and O'Rourke, 2007). By the eighteenth century, western Europe was no longer a peripheral appendage of the Eurasian landmass, but had become geographically and politically central. It was now in direct contact with all other regions of Eurasia, as well as with sub-Saharan Africa, but more importantly it controlled both North and South America, which were fully integrated into the world economy, importing slaves from Africa, exporting a variety of colonial goods to Europe, and exporting silver both to Europe and to Asia via the Philippines. As for eastern Europe, it was now in direct contact not just with central Asia and the Muslim world, but with east Asia and North America as well, as a result of Russia's Siberian conquests, which would prove to be the most enduring of all the European imperialisms of that time.",
author = "Kevin O'Rourke",
year = "2010",
month = "1",
day = "1",
doi = "10.1017/CBO9780511794834.006",
language = "English (US)",
isbn = "9780521882026",
pages = "96--121",
booktitle = "The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1",
publisher = "Cambridge University Press",

}

TY - CHAP

T1 - Trade and empire

AU - O'Rourke, Kevin

PY - 2010/1/1

Y1 - 2010/1/1

N2 - Introduction: the rise and fall of European mercantilism At the start of the first millennium, western Europe was the most peripheral region in Eurasia. Like Africa, its exports largely consisted of forest products and slaves, and it had direct economic links with just two other Eurasian regions – eastern Europe and the Islamic world. By contrast, the Islamic world had direct economic contacts with all the regions of the then known world: eastern and western Europe, sub-Saharan Africa, the steppe societies of central Asia, and the highly developed civilizations of south Asia, southeast Asia, and east Asia (Findlay and O'Rourke, 2007). By the eighteenth century, western Europe was no longer a peripheral appendage of the Eurasian landmass, but had become geographically and politically central. It was now in direct contact with all other regions of Eurasia, as well as with sub-Saharan Africa, but more importantly it controlled both North and South America, which were fully integrated into the world economy, importing slaves from Africa, exporting a variety of colonial goods to Europe, and exporting silver both to Europe and to Asia via the Philippines. As for eastern Europe, it was now in direct contact not just with central Asia and the Muslim world, but with east Asia and North America as well, as a result of Russia's Siberian conquests, which would prove to be the most enduring of all the European imperialisms of that time.

AB - Introduction: the rise and fall of European mercantilism At the start of the first millennium, western Europe was the most peripheral region in Eurasia. Like Africa, its exports largely consisted of forest products and slaves, and it had direct economic links with just two other Eurasian regions – eastern Europe and the Islamic world. By contrast, the Islamic world had direct economic contacts with all the regions of the then known world: eastern and western Europe, sub-Saharan Africa, the steppe societies of central Asia, and the highly developed civilizations of south Asia, southeast Asia, and east Asia (Findlay and O'Rourke, 2007). By the eighteenth century, western Europe was no longer a peripheral appendage of the Eurasian landmass, but had become geographically and politically central. It was now in direct contact with all other regions of Eurasia, as well as with sub-Saharan Africa, but more importantly it controlled both North and South America, which were fully integrated into the world economy, importing slaves from Africa, exporting a variety of colonial goods to Europe, and exporting silver both to Europe and to Asia via the Philippines. As for eastern Europe, it was now in direct contact not just with central Asia and the Muslim world, but with east Asia and North America as well, as a result of Russia's Siberian conquests, which would prove to be the most enduring of all the European imperialisms of that time.

UR - http://www.scopus.com/inward/record.url?scp=84889009501&partnerID=8YFLogxK

UR - http://www.scopus.com/inward/citedby.url?scp=84889009501&partnerID=8YFLogxK

U2 - 10.1017/CBO9780511794834.006

DO - 10.1017/CBO9780511794834.006

M3 - Chapter

AN - SCOPUS:84889009501

SN - 9780521882026

SP - 96

EP - 121

BT - The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Europe Volume 1

PB - Cambridge University Press

ER -